An Equilibrium Model of Institutional Demand and Asset Prices

Ralph S.J. Koijen, Ph.D., New York University Stern School of Business, CEPR and NBER, and Motohiro Yogo, Ph.D., Princeton University and NBER

Overview

While demand curves are an important part of economic theory, they have not played a large role in empirical asset pricing which has focused directly on prices and returns. Due largely to the empirical difficulty in estimating demand for financial securities, the finance literature has instead abstracted from the demands that drive prices. In this paper, the authors take up this ambitious and challenging task using a well-crafted model to tie price movements to demanded quantities (shares) in order to better understand asset market movements, volatility, and predictability. The authors develop a framework used extensively in industrial organization to model demand for U.S. stocks across different investors. They then use this model to back out expected return estimates that can help explain the role institutions play in driving asset price changes.

Investigation

Traditional asset pricing models make restrictive assumptions about investors’ demand. All investors have essentially the same preferences, beliefs, and constraints. Also, they are all price takers and as such have no price impact. The authors’ contribution is to develop a new factor-based asset pricing model that allows for investor heterogeneity and that matches asset prices with institutional holdings.

Merging data from quarterly SEC Form 13F institutional filings with CRSP-Compustat from 1980 to 2015, the authors model portfolio choice across six investor types (banks, investment advisors, pension funds, insurance companies, mutual funds, and households) as a function of five stock characteristics or factors identified in prior research (market beta, book equity, profitability, investment, and dividends to book equity) plus a structural error (latent demand). The authors illustrate estimating the demand system through several asset pricing applications:

  • Estimate the price impact of demand shocks for all institutions and stocks. They find that the price impact for typical institutions has meaningfully decreased from 1980 to 2014. For example, for a typical investment advisor with a 10 percent demand shock for illiquid stocks, their impact has decreased by 30% (from 0.87 percent in 1980 to 0.25 percent in 2014).
  • Separately estimate supply-side (i.e., changes in shares outstanding, changes in characteristics) and demand-side (i.e., changes in assets under management, loadings on characteristics) effects. The authors find that stock returns are mostly explained by latent demand shocks, not by changes in shares outstanding or changes in stock characteristics.
  • Examine to what extent large institutions explain the stock market volatility experienced in 2008. They discover that the largest 25 institutions, which together account for one-third of the stock market, explain only 6 percent of the cross sectional volatility of stock returns. Smaller institutions, which also account for one-third of the market, however, explain 42 percent of cross sectional volatility. Interestingly, households which account for the remaining one-third of the market, explain 48 percent of volatility. The relatively low contribution of large institutional investors likely reflects their long-term, diversified holdings of more liquid stocks.
  • Use the factor-based model to estimate expected returns for individual stocks. Results here are largely consistent with extant research — high expected-return stocks tend to be small-cap value stocks.

The model the authors develop could be used to answer additional important questions related to the role of institutions in asset markets, yet would be difficult to answer with traditional regression, or event-based approaches. They suggest such applications could include answering regulatory questions like: How would a regulatory proposal, say bank reform, affect asset prices and real investment, or how might quantitative easing impact fixed income markets? It could also be used to answer questions about asset pricing such as: Which investor groups drive anomalous stock returns identified in academic research?

Conclusions

The authors develop a new empirical asset pricing framework that models demand across a variety of investor types. They show how their approach can be used to address important issues relevant to finance regulators and practitioners such as examining the contribution of large institutions to market volatility as well as their impact on prices and liquidity. They also use it to estimate the cross section of stock returns and what factors or characteristics contribute to (and to what degree) returns and volatility. Finally, the authors discuss additional important questions that the model could help answer for both financial regulators and practitioners.

Read the paper

This document is not intended to, and does not relate specifically to any investment strategy or product that AQR offers. It is being provided merely to provide a framework to assist in the implementation of an investor’s own analysis and an investor’s own view on the topic discussed herein.

This document has been provided to you solely for information purposes and does not constitute an offer or solicitation of an offer or any advice or recommendation to purchase any securities or other financial instruments and may not be construed as such. The factual information set forth herein has been obtained or derived from sources believed by the author and AQR Capital Management, LLC (“AQR”) to be reliable but it is not necessarily all-inclusive and is not guaranteed as to its accuracy and is not to be regarded as a representation or warranty, express or implied, as to the information’s accuracy or completeness, nor should the attached information serve as the basis of any investment decision. This document is not to be reproduced or redistributed to any other person. The information set forth herein has been provided to you as secondary information and should not be the primary source for any investment or allocation decision. Past performance is not a guarantee of future performance. Diversification does not eliminate the risk of experiencing investment losses. 

This material is not research and should not be treated as research. This paper does not represent valuation judgments with respect to any financial instrument, issuer, security or sector that may be described or referenced herein and does not represent a formal or official view of AQR. The views expressed reflect the current views as of the date hereof and neither the author nor AQR undertakes to advise you of any changes in the views expressed herein. 

The information contained herein is only as current as of the date indicated, and may be superseded by subsequent market events or for other reasons. Charts and graphs provided herein are for illustrative purposes only. The information in this presentation has been developed internally and/or obtained from sources believed to be reliable; however, neither AQR nor the author guarantees the accuracy, adequacy or completeness of such information. Nothing contained herein constitutes investment, legal, tax or other advice nor is it to be relied on in making an investment or other decision. There can be no assurance that an investment strategy will be successful. Historic market trends are not reliable indicators of actual future market behavior or future performance of any particular investment which may differ materially, and should not be relied upon as such. Diversification does not eliminate the risk of experiencing investment losses.

The information in this paper may contain projections or other forward-looking statements regarding future events, targets, forecasts or expectations regarding the strategies described herein, and is only current as of the date indicated. There is no assurance that such events or targets will be achieved, and may be significantly different from that shown here. The information in this document, including statements concerning financial market trends, is based on current market conditions, which will fluctuate and may be superseded by subsequent market events or for other reasons.